版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
WhySouthKoreaShouldResistNew
DigitalPlatformLaws
LILLANóRAKISS|DECEMBER2024
PolicymakersinSouthKoreaareweighingaraftofdigitalmarketprovisionsinspiredbytheEU’sDigitalMarketsAct.TheirgoalistoreininallegedlyanticompetitivepracticesbyBigTechfirms.Buttheproposedinterventionsareunwarrantedandriskharminginnovation,strainingrelationswiththeUnitedStatesduringuncertaintimes,andopeningthedoortoChina.
KEYTAKEAWAYS
SouthKoreaaimstoprotectsmallfirms,butitdoesnotneedDMA-styleprovisions.Itsthrivingdigitalmarketsshownosignsoffailure,andtheKFTCalreadyenforceslawseffectivelytocurbanticompetitivebehavior.
Policymakersarguepracticessuchasself-preferencing,tying,multi-hominglimits,andMFNclausesstiflecompetitionandharmsmallerrivals.Buttheyoftenenhance
efficiency,preventfree-riding,anddeliversafe,high-qualityservicestoconsumers.
ProposedreformsmodeledaftertheEU-DMA’sprovisionscouldstifleinnovation,raisecosts,andreduceuserbenefits.Insteadofdrivingcompetition,theyriskharming
consumersandunderminingefficiency.
SouthKorea’sproposedreformsrestrictingcommonplatformpracticestargetlargeU.S.andSouthKoreanfirms,stiflinginnovationandexemptingsmallerrivalswhileinvitingChinesefirmstofillthevoid.
WithU.S.electionsover,SouthKorearisksabacklashfromanewadministrationunlikelytotoleratepoliciesthatharmmajorU.S.businesses.DMA-likereformsalsopose
economicandsecurityrisksbygivingChinesefirmsastrongerfootholdthere.
SouthKoreareliesonU.S.supporttobealeaderinIT,telecom,semiconductors,and
defense.AlienatingAmericaunderminesitsregionalleadershipandweakeningitsabilitytocountergrowingsecuritythreatsandeconomiccompetitionfromChina.
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE2
CONTENTS
KeyTakeaways 1
Introduction 3
PolicyBackground 3
Policymakers’VariousRationalesforPlatformRegulation 5
ConcernsThatDigitalMarketsAreDifferent,andThereforeNeedNewRules 5
TheArgumentThatPracticesUniquetoPlatformsAreUnfairtoCompetitors 6
TheConcernThatSmallFirmsShouldBeProtected 13
TheUrgetoProtectCompetitorsInsteadofConsumers 14
OverallProblemsWithSouthKoreanDigitalPlatformLaws 15
TheProposedReformsWillHarmConsumers 15
TheProposedReformsWillChillInnovation 15
TheProposedReformsCanLeadtoRegulatoryCapture 16
TheProposedReformsCanFavorChina 16
RegulationsCanHaveNegativeEffectsonU.S.-SouthKoreanRelations 18
RecommendationsforaPro-innovationformula 19
DoNotAdoptDMA-StyleRules(NeitherExAntenorExPost) 19
UseExistingLawstoSolveAntitrustCasesandUseOtherSectoralLawstoHandle
NoncompetitionIssues 19
AmendExistingLaws—ButNotintheWayProposed 19
Conclusion 20
Appendix:MainSouthKoreanDigitalCompetitionProposals 21
Endnotes 22
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE3
INTRODUCTION
Inthelastdecade,policymakers,particularlythoseintheEU,havearguedthatanewtypeofbusinessmodel—Internetplatforms,oftenperceivedashavingwinner-take-allcharacteristics—requiresfundamentallynewapproachestocompetitionpolicy.
1
Theselargefirmsseem,atfirst,topolicymakersasanewstrangekindofspeciescallingforanewkindoflegislativeand
regulatoryresponse.Neitherclaimistrue.
Brusselsledthewayinframingtheissuethiswayandcraftingunprecedented(andunneeded)legislation.ThroughtheDigitalMarketsAct(DMA)—alawsettingstrict,exante,rulesforlargeonlineplatforms(“gatekeepers”)—theEUsquarelyfocusesonlargetechcompaniesby
establishingthresholdsthatalignwiththeclaimedmarketpowerofU.S.techgiantssuchas
Google,Amazon,Apple,Facebook,andMicrosoft.
2
AndreasSchwab,theEuropeanParliament’srapporteurfortheDMA,hasstatedthattheregulationshouldfocusonthesetopAmerican
companiesratherthanexpandingtoincludeEuropeanfirms,fordiplomaticappeasement.
3
Throughthe“BrusselsEffect,”ortheEU’sglobalregulatoryinfluence,SouthKorea(andseveralothercountries)arerethinkingtheircompetitionpolicyasitappliestodigitalmarkets.The
DMA’sexanteprovisionsmarkashiftincompetitionenforcementbyproactivelyimposing
measuresongatekeeperstopreventanticompetitivebehaviorbeforeitoccurs,movingawayfromthetraditionalexpostlawenforcementapproach,whichreactstoviolationsonlyaftertheyaredetected.Butevenifthesereformswereenactedthroughamendmentstotheexisting
competitionrules,theyareproblematicbecausemanyofthebehaviorsofconcernarepro-
consumerandpro-innovation.TheDMAisbadpolicy,andSouthKorea’semulationofit,eveninitsmodifiedproposedexpostway,wouldalsobebadpolicy.
ThisreportfocusesonSouthKorea’sconcernsmotivatingitsdesireforanewcompetitionlawfordigitalplatforms.Itevaluatesthenecessityoftheseinterventions,analyzespotentialunintendedconsequencesforbothdomesticandinternationaltechindustries,andexploresthegeopoliticalimplications,especiallyregardingU.S.-SouthKoreanrelationsandtheincreasinginfluenceof
Chinesefirmsintheregion.
POLICYBACKGROUND
InJanuary2024,theNationalPolicyCommitteeoftheKoreanNationalAssemblyhad19digitalplatform-focusedbillsonitslegislativeagenda,eachofwhichhadthreecommonobjectives:
1.Identifythe“gatekeepers,”knownas“dominantoperators”
2.Regulatetheirpresumptivelyanticompetitiveconduct
3.Enhanceconsumerprotectionbyrequiringplatformstoprovideclearadvancenoticeofanysignificantchangestotheirservices
Asofthisreport,someoftheseexantebillshavebeendropped.
InadditiontotheexantereformsalreadypendingbeforeParliament,onOctober28,2024,Rep.Min-kookKang,alongwith11otherrepresentativesoftherulingPeoplePowerParty(PPP),
introducedthePartialAmendmentBilltotheMonopolyRegulationandFairTradeAct(MRFTA)(PartialAmendmentBill4947).ItisbasedontheKoreaFairTradeCommission’s(KFTC’s)newplanrevealedthispastSeptembertoamendtheexisting(expost)laws,namely,theMRFTAand
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE4
theLargeScaleRetailBusinessAct(LSRBA).
4
Thebillaimstostrengthencompetitionlaws,
particularlyastheyapplytoonlineplatforms.
5
TheMRFTAgenerallyaimstoprevent
monopolisticpractices,regulateanticompetitivebehaviors,andensurefairmarketcompetition.Ittacklesabusesofmarketdominance,unfairbusinesspractices,andmergersoracquisitions
thatcouldharmcompetitiveconditions.
6
ThePartialAmendmentBill,contrarytotheoriginal
intentionsoftheKFTC,doesnotmentionthemodificationoftheLSRBA.Thislawisintendedtoprotectsmallerretailersandsuppliersfrompurportedlyunfairpracticesbylarge-scaleretailers.
7
SimilarlytotheEU’sgatekeeperdesignation,theKFTC’samendmenttotheMRFTAaimsto
categorizeplatformsas“dominantonlineplatformoperators”basedondetailedcriteria.A
platformoperatorwillbepresumeddominantifithasatleasta60percentmarketshareina
relevantserviceareaandanaverageof10millionmonthlyactiveusers(MAU)overthreeyears.Additionally,ifthetopthreeoperatorsinamarketholdacombinedmarketshareof85percentormore,anyoperatorwithinthisgroupwithatleasta20percentshareand20millionMAUwillalsobepresumeddominant.However,operatorsareexemptfromthispresumptioniftheirtotalsalesfromplatformservicesandrelatedgoodsarebelowKRW3trillion(~$2.16million).
Designateddominantplatformsaresubjecttostrictregulationstopreventallegedly
anticompetitivepracticesacrosssixcoreserviceareas:intermediaries,searchengines,socialmedia,videostreaming,operatingsystems,andadvertising.ThePartialAmendmentBill
prohibitstheseplatformsfromengaginginseveralcommonpractices:
.Self-preferencing:favoringtheirownproductsorservicesoverthoseofcompetitors).Tying/bundling:requiringuserstopurchaseadditionalproductsorservices
.Most-favorednation(MFN)clauses:mandatingequalorbettertermsthanthoseofferedonotherplatforms
.Multi-homingrestrictions:preventingusersfromusingcompetingplatforms
SimilarlytotheEU’sgatekeeperdesignation,theKFTC’samendmenttotheMRFTAaimstocategorizeplatformsas“dominantonlineplatformoperators”basedondetailedcriteria.
UnderthePartialAmendmentBill,thedominantonlineplatformoperatorsbeartheburdenof
prooftoprovidepro-competitivejustifications,suchasbydemonstratingconsumerwelfaregainsorsecurityrequirements.Absentsuchproof,practicesarepresumedtobeanticompetitiveandipsojureprohibited.Thisapproachcontrastswiththerule-of-reasonapproachinU.S.antitrustlaw,whereinauthoritiesmustfirstestablishthatconductisanticompetitivebeforecompanies
arerequiredtoofferpro-competitivejustifications.TheabsenceofsucharequirementinSouthKoreaiscontroversial,asitshiftstheevidentiaryburdenontoplatformswithoutrequiring
authoritiestodemonstrateharmtocompetition.
AlthoughthePartialAmendmentBillseemslikeacompromisebetweenexanteandexpost
approaches,itisnotasignificantdeparturefromDMA-style(exante)regulations.ThereasonisthatitretainsproblematicprovisionsofDMA-likelaws,suchasdesignatingdominantoperatorsandrestrictingtheirotherwisepro-competitivepractices(e.g.,self-preferencing,tying),and,asofNovember2024,itappearstounfairlytargetU.S.andSouthKoreancompaniessuchasGoogle,
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE5
Apple,Kakao,Naver,andBaemin(basedonexcludingplatformswithdirectandindirectsalesoflessthanKRW3trillionor~$2.16million).
ThePartialAmendmentBillisseeminglygainingsupportfromtheYoonadministration.
Oppositionparties,includingtheDemocraticParty(DP)continuedraftingtheirownexantebills.TheconcurrentproposalsforbothexanteandexpostlawsinSouthKorea,withthepossibilityofbothpassingthroughtheNationalAssembly,revealalackofclearvisioninthecountry’spolicydirection.
SouthKorea—byconsideringmultipleexantebills—seeminglyfollowsEurope’sexampleby
adoptingstrictprovisionsfordigitalplatformswithoutconsideringalternativestolegislation.
Singapore,Taiwan,andtheUnitedStates,forexample,haveoptednottoimplementproactive,DMA-styleregulationsandinsteadrelyontheirexistingantitrustlawsandexpostenforcementofanticompetitivepractices.TheDMAisjustone,andnottheonly,solutionfortacklingdigital
platforms.
Together,SouthKorea’s19digitallawproposalsrevealafragmentedandunclearpolicyvision.
POLICYMAKERS’VARIOUSRATIONALESFORPLATFORMREGULATION
TherealrationaleforSouthKorea’s(andotherjurisdictions’)digitalcompetitionpolicyproposalsvaries,regardlessofwhethertheyareexanteorexpost.Thebillsseemtotargetpresumptivelyanticompetitivebehavior,butinaslightlydifferentway.Regardlessofdiscussingexantereformsorexpostamendmentsforthedigitalcompetitionpolicy,theprovidedrationaleforsuchreformslacksevidence-basedjustifications.
ConcernsThatDigitalMarketsAreDifferent,andThereforeNeedNewRules
Thepushforstricterregulationsindigitalmarketsoftenarisesfromconcernsthatlargeplatformsmaymonopolizeamarketduetostrongnetworkeffects,whereineachadditionaluserincreasesaplatform’svalue;andthereisa“winner-takes-all”phenomenonwhereinthemostpopular
platformcapturesnearlyallusers.
8
However,theassumptionthatdigitalmarketsareuniqueandthereforerequiredistinctregulatorymeasuresmisrepresentstheirunderlyingdynamics.It
incorrectlyassumesthatthesedifferencesfromtraditionalmarketsjustifynew,sweeping
regulatorymeasures.Butdigitalmarketsarenotinherentlydifferentinawaythatrequires
distinctregulations,especiallyintheabsenceofdemonstratedmarketfailures.Tothecontrary:
.Scaleisafeatureandnotaflawofdigitalmarkets.Networkeffectsshouldbeseenasanaturalpartofdigitalcompetition,ratherthanasanticompetitivedominance.
9
.Digitalmarketsareshapedbymorethanjustscale;companiesinvestinbetteruser
experiencestoattractandretainconsumers,fosteringinnovationandchoice.The
competitionforuserengagementandthetransientnatureofconsumerpreferenceskeepsdigitalmarketsdynamic.InSouthKorea,platformssuchasCoupangandNaverhave
thrivedpreciselyduetotheirabilitytoscaleandcaptureconsumerattention,drivinggrowthandcompetitiveness.
.Regardlessofwhetherdigitalmarketsaredifferentfromtraditionalmarkets,newrulesarenotjustifiedunlessthereismarketfailure.Intheabsenceofevidenceofmarketfailure,
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE6
jurisdictionsshouldnotadopteconomicregulations.Marketfailureariseswhenamarketrepeatedlyfailstoallocateresourcesefficiently,resultingininefficienciesandharmingconsumers.Thetimefactorishighlyrelevantinassessingmarketfailure,assuchfailuresmustreflectsustainedorrecurringinefficienciesratherthanshort-termdisruptionsor
temporaryimbalances.Amarketmayexperiencebriefperiodsofdominanceor
inefficiency,butthesealonedonotconstitutemarketfailureifcompetitivedynamicsandinnovationnaturallyresolvethemovertime.Indeed,truemarketfailurerequires
persistentandsystemicissuesthatcontinuetoharmconsumerwelfarewithoutcorrectionbymarketforces.
However,SouthKorea’sdigitalmarketsarethrivingwithremarkablegrowth,innovation,andcompetitivenesswithoutexcessiveregulatoryintervention.Keysectorssuchase-
commerce,semiconductors,andartificialintelligence(AI)continuetopropelSouthKoreaasagloballeaderintechnology,withmajorfirmssuchasSamsung,SKHynix,andLG
reinforcingitspositionasatechpowerhouse.PlatformssuchasCoupang,Naver,andGmarketarealsoflourishing,withtheinformationandcommunicationtechnologies
industrycontributingnearlyKRW68trillion(~$48.6billion)togrossdomesticproduct(GDP)inQ42023.
10
Currently,nosignsofmarketfailurethreatenSouthKorea’s
efficientresourceallocation.
.Eveninthecaseofmarketfailure,SouthKoreashouldfocusontargeted,specific
interventionswherenecessary;policymakersshouldnotimposeblanketbansoncertain
practices.Heavy-handedregulationisparticularlyharmfulindigitalmarketsbecausethesemarketsaredynamic,fastevolving,anddrivenbyrapidinnovationcycles.Overlybroadorrestrictivemeasurescanalsostifleinnovationbycreatingcomplianceburdensthatdivertresourcesawayfromresearchanddevelopment.
11
Additionally,such
regulationsoftenfailtoaccountforthetransientnatureofmarketpowerindigital
platforms,whereinfirmsfrequentlyriseandfallduetocompetitionandtechnologicaladvancements.
12
Broadregulatoryinterventionsareoftenineffectiveinaddressing
specificmarketconcerns,whichcantypicallyberesolvedthroughexistinglawsorminor—moresurgical—regulatoryadjustments.
.Finally,issuessuchasconsumerprotection,dataprivacy,andunfairtradingpracticescouldbemanagedwithinSouthKorea’scurrentregulatoryframework.Forinstance,refining
consumerprotectionlawstoaddressparticularincidentswouldbemoreappropriatethaninstitutingbroadbansorrestrictionsthatdiscriminatebasedonthesizeoftheplatforms.
SouthKoreashouldfirstidentifyspecificmarketissuesandapplytailoredlegalremediesto
avoidunintendedconsequences,suchasoverregulation.Therefore,new,expansiverulesare
unwarrantedandpotentiallydetrimental(regardlessofbeingwrappedinexanteorexpost
legislativeproducts),asthereisinsufficientevidenceofmarketfailurethatwouldjustifysuchanintervention.
TheArgumentThatPracticesUniquetoPlatformsAreUnfairtoCompetitors
EUcompetitionofficialshavearguedthatcertainpracticesofonlineplatformsareinherently
unfairtocompetitorsand,itshouldbenoted,notasharmfultoconsumerwelfare.
13
South
Koreanofficialsappeartoberaisingthesameconcerns.
14
BoththeexantebillsandthePartialAmendmentBillcriticizeself-preferencing,tyingandbundling,most-favored-nationclauses,and
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE7
multi-homingrestrictions.Thesepracticesarepresumedtobeanticompetitiveinboththeexanteandexpostbills.
Self-Preferencing
Self-preferencingsoundsnefarious,butitsimplyreferstoconsumer-facingcompanies
prioritizingtheirownproductsorservices,potentiallyofferingconsumersstreamlinedcosts,
improvedservicedelivery,andanenhanceduserexperience.Forexample,aplatformmay
promoteitsownproductsatthetopinsearchresultsorofferexclusiveservices,oftenleadingtobetterprices,fasterdelivery,andimprovedconvenienceforusers.Byenablingfirmstoinnovatewithintheirecosystems,self-preferencingcanoftenfosterconsumerchoiceandsatisfaction.
15
Self-preferencingisnotnew.Grocerystoresoftenputtheirownstorebrandsattheidealheightontheirshelveswhereconsumersaremostlikelytobuythem.Ifthiswereanticonsumer,
consumerswouldchooseotherstores.Thus,self-preferencingbyplatformsalmostalwaysisconsumerwelfareenhancing.
InSouthKorea,regulatorshaveraisedself-preferencingasaconcernwithinproposed
competitionpolicyreforms.Theirprimaryworryisthatlargeplatformsmightuseself-
preferencingtolimitcompetition,possiblydisadvantagingsmallercompetitorsandreducingmarketdiversity.
Butregulatorsshouldonlybefocusedonself-preferencingifitexcludescompetitorsandharmsconsumerwelfare.Forexample,leadingsearchcompaniesmightoffertheirownresultsatthe
topofsearchresults.Aslongasthisiscleartoconsumers,thereisnothingunfairaboutit.At
thesametime,mostsearchcompaniesallowcompetitorstopurchasespaceatthetopofthe
page,againaslabeledadvertising.Andfinally,competitors’resultsmayshowupin“organic”
searchesthatalgorithmsdetermine.Aslongasasearchplatformdoesnotbanacompetitorfromadvertisinganddoesnotintentionallydegradecompetitors’positionsinorganicsearches,thereshouldbenoreasonforregulatorstobeconcerned.
Self-preferencingsoundsnefarious,butitsimplyreferstoconsumer-facingcompaniesprioritizingtheirownproductsorservices,potentiallyofferingconsumersstreamlinedcosts,improvedservicedelivery,andanenhanceduserexperience.
Whileself-preferencingcould,insomecases,disadvantagesmallerplayers,therealissueisthatitusuallyprovidessignificantconsumerbenefits.Blanketprohibitionsonself-preferencing,suchasthoseproposedinSouthKorea’sexantebills,riskstiflingtheseadvantagesbytreatingall
self-preferencingasinherentlyharmful.Suchbroadbanscanresultin“falsepositives,”
penalizingconsumer-friendlypracticesalongsidepotentiallyanticompetitiveones.
16
Byassumingthatallself-preferencinginherentlyharmscompetition,theserestrictionsfocusonprotecting
competitorsinsteadofconsumersandoverlookcaseswheretheconductclearlyservesconsumerinterests.
Moreover,ablanketprohibitionoftheexantebillscouldharmconsumers,suchasthe
restrictionssetintheproposedexpostreform.Self-preferencingisoftenanefficientand
competitivelyneutralstrategy,especiallyindigitalmarketswherestrongnetworkeffectsandrapidinnovationcyclesdriveplatformstoimproveandcustomizeservices.Imposingstrict
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE8
restrictionsonself-preferencingcoulddisruptthisbalanceofcompetitionandinnovation,discouragingplatformsfrominvestinginenhancementsthatcouldbenefitusers.
Inlightofthesefactors,regulationsonself-preferencingshouldfocusonevidence-basedanalysis
ratherthanblanketprohibitionsorrestrictionsthatputtheinitialburdenoncompaniestoshowpro-competitivejustificationswithoutrequiringtheauthoritiestoshowharmfirst.Regulators
coulddistinguishbetweenpracticesthatgenuinelyharmcompetitionandthosethatsupportconsumerwelfare,thusensuringthatthebenefitsofself-preferencingarenotlostdueto
overregulation.
17
TyingandBundling
Tyingandbundlingrefertopracticesinwhichaplatformlinksthesaleofaprimaryproductto
additionalgoodsorservices.Tying(apracticewhereinthepurchaseofoneproductis
conditionedonthepurchaseofanotherdistinctproduct)andbundling(theofferingoftwoor
moreproductstogetherasapackage,oftenatadiscountedprice)canoftenbenefitconsumersbyprovidingconvenience,reducingtransactioncosts,andsometimesloweringoverallprices.Forexample,platformsmightbundlecomplementaryservices—suchasstorageorcustomer
support—withacoreoffering,whichstreamlinesuserexperienceanddeliversadditionalvalue.
18
Forinstance,Apple’sbundlingofitsproprietaryhardware(e.g.,iPhones)withiOSandother
built-inapplicationshasbeensuccessfulbecausedoingsoenhancesfunctionality,security,andtheuserexperience.
Tyingandbundlingcanoftenbenefitconsumersbyprovidingconvenience,reducingtransactioncosts,andsometimesloweringoverallprices.
InSouthKorea,regulatorshaveraisedtyingandbundlingasaconcernwithintheframeworkofdigitalmarketcompetition.Theirprimaryworryisthatdominantplatformsmightusethese
practicestoleveragetheirpositioninonemarkettoestablishdominanceinanother,creating
barrierstoentryforcompetitorsinadjacentmarkets.Aprominentexampleistheseriesof
antitrustcasesagainstMicrosoftintheEuropeanUnion,whichaddresseddifferentinstancesofbundlingpractices.InCaseT-201/04,theEuropeanCommissionruledthatMicrosoft’sbundlingofWindowsMediaPlayerwithitsdominantWindowsoperatingsystemharmedcompetitioninthemediaplayermarketbyexcludingrivalproductsandlimitingconsumerchoice.
19
Separately,inCaseCOMP/C-3/37.792(notifiedunderCaseT-167/08),thecommissionfoundthatMicrosoft’styingofInternetExplorerwithWindowsstifledcompetitioninthewebbrowsermarket,deprivingconsumersofalternativebrowseroptions.
20
Whilecertainformsofthesepracticescouldreducecompetition,tyingandbundlingfrequentlyhelpconsumers,oftenenhancingconsumerwelfarebycreatingefficient,integratedservice
optionsthatconsumersprefer.Strictrestrictionsontyingandbundlingriskcreatingfalse
positives,resultinginaregulatoryapproachthatprioritizescompetitorprotectionoverconsumerwelfare,ignoringthepracticalefficienciesthatmanytyingorbundlingpracticesprovide.
21
Thedigitaleconomythrivesonrapidinnovationandstrongnetworkeffects;prohibitingintegrated
servicesolutionscoulddiscourageplatformsfrominvestinginvaluableimprovements,ultimatelyproducingachillingeffectoninnovation.Asaresult,consumersmayloseaccesstoefficient,
high-qualityservicesplatformscouldotherwisedevelop.
INFORMATIONTECHNOLOGY&INNOVATIONFOUNDATION|DECEMBER2024PAGE9
Giventhesefactors,regulationsontyingandbundlingshouldfocusonevidence-basedanalysisratherthanblanketprohibitionsenshrinedintheexantebillsorrestrictionsintroducedtocontrolthepracticesoflargetechcompanieswithoutrequiringtheauthoritiestoestablishharmfirst.
Regulatorsshoulddistinguishbetweenpracticesthataregenuinelyanticompetitiveandharmconsumersversusthosethatenhanceconsumerwelfare.
Most-FavoredNationClauses
MFNclausesrefertoagreementswhereinaplatformrequiressuppliersorsellerstoprovideitwithtermsasfavorableasthoseofferedtoanyotherplatform.Theseclausescanbenefit
consumersbyensuringthataplatform’susersgetthebestavailableterms.Whenplatforms
leverageMFNclauses,theycannegotiatelowerpricesorsecureexclusivedeals,oftenresultinginlowercosts,betterqualityofferings,andincreasedconsumerchoice.
InSouthKorea,regulatorshaveraisedMFNclausesasaconcern,particularlyregarding
dominantplatforms.TheirconcernisthatlargeplatformsmightuseMFNclausestorestrictcompetitionbypreventingsuppliersfromofferingbettertermstootherplatforms,therebylimitingopportunitiesforsmallerplayersornewentrantstodifferentiatethemselves.
However,thisconcernmaybeoverstated.WhileMFNclausescan,incertaincases,restrict
competition,theyalsoprovidesignificantconsumerbenefits.Bynegotiatingthemostfavorableterms,platformscanpassonlowerpricesandenhancedvaluetoconsumers,whichcandrivecompetitioninqualityandpricingacrossthemarket.BlanketprohibitionsonMFNclausesthusriskpenalizingconsumer-friendlypractices,creatingfalsepositiveswhereinbeneficialusesofMFNsarerestrictedalongsidepotentiallyanticompetitiveones.SuchanapproachassumesthatMFNclausesareinherentlyharmful,overlookingscenariosinwhichtheyactuallyimprove
consumerwelfare.
MFNclausescanbenefitconsumersbyensuringthataplatform’susersgetthebestavailableterms.
ProhibitingMFNclausescanbeharmfultoconsumers.WithouttheabilitytouseMFNclauses,platformsmaylosebargainingpower,whichcouldleadtohigherprices,fewerchoices,orlower-qualityofferingsforconsumers.Forinstance,intheonlinebookingmarket,whensuppliershavegreaterbargainingpower,MFNclausescanyieldpro-competitiveeffects,enhancingefficiencyandconsumerwelfare.
22
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 煙草制品健康風(fēng)險(xiǎn)評(píng)估-洞察分析
- 消費(fèi)者醫(yī)療需求預(yù)測(cè)模型-洞察分析
- 醫(yī)務(wù)工作人員態(tài)度不好檢討書(shū)范文(15篇)
- 系統(tǒng)生物學(xué)統(tǒng)計(jì)分析-洞察分析
- 響應(yīng)式多語(yǔ)言菜單設(shè)計(jì)-洞察分析
- 新能源設(shè)備可靠性-洞察分析
- 物流行業(yè)數(shù)字化轉(zhuǎn)型-第1篇-洞察分析
- 網(wǎng)吧行業(yè)個(gè)性化服務(wù)策略-洞察分析
- 關(guān)于學(xué)校欺凌的發(fā)言稿范文(6篇)
- 從零到一的創(chuàng)新過(guò)程-XX產(chǎn)品的誕生與發(fā)展
- 醫(yī)療陪護(hù)行業(yè)前景分析報(bào)告
- 個(gè)體診所藥品清單模板
- 有機(jī)更新工作總結(jié)
- eviews操作說(shuō)明課件
- 教師法律法規(guī)講座課件
- 壓機(jī)操作工安全操作規(guī)程范本
- 大學(xué)《營(yíng)養(yǎng)與膳食》考試復(fù)習(xí)題庫(kù)(含答案)
- 戰(zhàn)場(chǎng)偵察課件
- 2023年道德與法治的教學(xué)個(gè)人工作總結(jié)
- GB 31241-2022便攜式電子產(chǎn)品用鋰離子電池和電池組安全技術(shù)規(guī)范
- 2024年華潤(rùn)集團(tuán)招聘筆試參考題庫(kù)含答案解析
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論