歐洲央行-能源價(jià)格沖擊、貨幣政策和不平等(英)_第1頁
歐洲央行-能源價(jià)格沖擊、貨幣政策和不平等(英)_第2頁
歐洲央行-能源價(jià)格沖擊、貨幣政策和不平等(英)_第3頁
歐洲央行-能源價(jià)格沖擊、貨幣政策和不平等(英)_第4頁
歐洲央行-能源價(jià)格沖擊、貨幣政策和不平等(英)_第5頁
已閱讀5頁,還剩75頁未讀, 繼續(xù)免費(fèi)閱讀

下載本文檔

版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)

文檔簡介

EUROPEANCENTRALBANK

EUROSYSTEM

WorkingPaperSeries

AlinaBobasu,MichaelDobrew,AmaliaRepeleEnergypriceshocks,monetarypolicyandinequality

No2967

Disclaimer:ThispapershouldnotbereportedasrepresentingtheviewsoftheEuropeanCentralBank(ECB).TheviewsexpressedarethoseoftheauthorsanddonotnecessarilyreflectthoseoftheECB.

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29671

Abstract

Westudyhowmonetarypolicyshapestheaggregateanddistributionaleffectsof

anenergypriceshock.Basedontheobservedheterogeneityinconsumptionexpo-surestoenergyandhouseholdwealth,webuildaquantitativesmallopen-economyHANKmodelthatmatchessalientfeaturesoftheEuroAreadata.Ourmodelin-corporatesenergyasbothaconsumptiongoodforhouseholdswithnon-homotheticpreferencesaswellasafactorinputintoproductionwithinputcomplementarities.

Independentlyofpolicyenergypriceshocksalwaysreduceaggregateconsumption.Householdswithlittlewealtharemoreadverselyaffectedthroughbothadeclineinlaborincomeaswellasnegativedirectpriceeffects.Activepolicyresponsesraisingratesinresponsetoinflationamplifiesaggregateoutcomesthroughareductioninaggregatedemand,butspeedsuptherecoverybyenablinghouseholdstorebuildwealththroughhigherreturnsonsavings.However,low-wealthhouseholdsarefur-theradverselyaffectedastheyhavelittlesavingstorebuildwealthfromandinsteadlooseduetofurtherdeclininglaborincome.

Keywords:energyprices,openeconomymodel,heterogeneousagents,monetarypolicy,non-homotheticpreferences.

JEL-Classification:E52,F41,Q43.

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29672

Non-technicalsummary

Inthispaperweinvestigatetheaggregateanddistributionaleffectsofenergypriceshocksandhowtheyareshapedbymonetarypolicy.Basedontheobservedheterogeneityinhouseholdconsumptionexposurestoenergyandwealthpositions,webuildasmallopeneconomyhet-erogeneousagentNewKeynesian(HANK)modelcalibratedtoEuroAreadata.Ourmodelincorporatesenergyasbothaconsumptiongoodforhouseholdswithnon-homotheticprefer-encesaswellasafactorinputintoproductionwithinputcomplementarities.Allenergyusedinthedomesticeconomyhastobeimported.Wecontrast“passive”monetarypolicyresponsesthatkeeptherealinterestrate(nearly)constantwith“active”policyresponsesthatreacttoinflationbystronglyraisingtherealrate.

Ourmainfindingscanbesummarisedasfollows.First,energypriceincreasesadverselyaffectthedomesticeconomyregardlessofthemonetarypolicyresponse.Asallenergyhastobeimported,risingenergypriceseffectivelyconstituteatransferofwealthfromthedomestictotheforeigneconomy.Incontrasttoapassivepolicyresponse,anactivepolicyreactionraisingtherealratetofightinflationimpliesafourtimeslargerdeclineinaggregateconsumption.

Second,weshowthatthedriversoftheaggregateconsumptionresponsediffersubstantiallybetweenactiveandpassivemonetarypolicyresponses.Wedecomposetheaggregateconsump-tionresponseintothreecomponents,adirecteffectstemmingfromchangesintherealinterestrate,anindirecteffectresultingfromchangesinreallaborincome,andarelativepriceeffect.Underapassivepolicyresponse,four-fifthsoftheconsumptiondeclineisattributedtoindirectincomeeffects,whiletherestisdrivenbytherelativepriceeffect.Instarkcontrast,underanactivepolicyresponsethree-fourthsofthedeclineinconsumptionisexplainedbythedirectrealrateeffectandthereforedirectlyrelatedtomonetarypolicy.

Third,low-wealthhouseholdsaregenerallyaffectedthemostbyanenergypriceincrease.Absentanypolicyresponsethedeclineinconsumptionisthreetimeslargerforlow-relativetohigh-wealthhouseholds.Anactivepolicyresponseamplifiestheconsumptiondeclineforallhouseholds.Althoughtherelativedeclineislargerforwealthierhouseholds,theunderlyingdriversdifferstarkly.Low-wealthhouseholdshavetoreduceconsumptionbecauseofthefurtherdeclineinlaborincomeduetofallingeconomicactivity.Incontrast,high-wealthhouseholdschoosetoreducetheirconsumptionbecauseahigherrealrateincentivizesthemtosavemore.

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29673

1Introduction

Energypriceshavereachedhistoricalheights,startingtheirriseinmid-2021aftermosteconomiesreopenedfromCOVID-19lockdownsandbeingcatalysedearly2022bytheRussianinvasionofUkraine.Figure

1

(leftpanel)showsthatrealenergypricesintheEuroAreahaverisenby60percentfromtheirlowsin2020andby30percentcomparedtotheiraverageoverthepast20years.Atthesametime,thetermsoftradedeterioratedwithnegativeimplicationsfordomesticpurchasingpower.DespitetheEuroAreabeinganenergyimporterfacinganexogenousshock,monetarypolicyreactedtotheenergypricesurgebyraisingratesatunprecedentedspeed.Theriseinenergypricesandsubsequentpolicyresponsenaturallyhaveheterogeneouseffectsonhouseholds,withlesswealthyhouseholdslikelybeingaffectedthemost.First,thesehouseholdsaremoreexposedtoenergypricesthroughtheirconsumptionbasketastheyspendalargerfractionoftheirincomeonenergy-relatedgoods(middlepanel).Second,theirlimitedsavingsmakesitdifficultforthemtosmooththeirconsumptioninresponsetotemporarypriceincreases(rightpanel)

.1

Third,low-wealthhouseholdsalmostsolelyrelyonlaborincomeanddonotbenefitfromhigherreturnsonsavings.

Figure1:Energyprices,termsoftrade,households’consumptionexposuresandsavingsacrosstheincomedistribution

permilleofconsumption

50

40

30

20

10

0

Energypricesandthetermsoftrade

130

120

110

100

90

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

2022

2024

RealenergypricesTermsoftrade(rhs)

102

101

100

99

98

Exposuretoenergyexpenditure

IIIIIIIVV

Incomequantiles

40

percentofdisposableincome

30

20

10

0

Savings

IIIIIIIVV

Incomequantiles

Note:The“realenergyprice”indicatestheratiobetweentheenergycomponentoftheHICPandtheoverallHICPindex.ThetermsoftradeareproxiedbytheratiobetweentheGDPdeflatorandtheprivate

consumptiondeflator.Chartsinthemiddleandrightarebasedondistributionalstatisticsfromthe“Householdbudgetsurvey“andtheexperimental“Income,consumption,andwealth”datasetsprovidedbyEurostat.

Basedontheobservedheterogeneityinhouseholdconsumptionandwealth,webuildasmall

1Formoredetailsonsmalleradjustmentmarginsforlow-incomehouseholdsgiventheirconsumptionbasketandsavingspositions,seealso

HobijnandLagakos

(2005),

Bobasuetal.

(2023)and

BilsandAguiar

(2010)

.

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29674

openeconomyheterogeneousagentNewKeynesian(HANK)modeltoanalysetheaggregateanddistributionaleffectsofenergypriceincreasesandhowtheseeffectsareshapedbymonetarypolicy.Weshowfirst,thatanenergypriceshockisalwaysrecessionaryinanopeneconomythatimportsallenergybecauseitconstitutesawealthtransferfromthedomestictotheforeigneconomy.Second,theinitialadverseaggregateeffectsaresmallerwhenmonetarypolicyremains“passive”,i.e.keepstherealrateconstant.“Active”monetarypolicyreactingtoinflationbyraisingtherealrateexacerbatestheinitialnegativeeffects,yetimpliesafasterrecovery.Bydecomposingtheaggregateconsumptionresponseweshowthatunderapassivepolicythenegativeeffectsofenergypriceshocksmainlyarisethroughnegativerealincomeeffects.Incontrast,underanactivepolicyconsumptiondeclinespredominantlyduetoarisingrealrateinsteadoftheshockitself.Third,low-wealthhouseholdsareaffectedthemostbyanenergypriceshock.Activepolicyexacerbatesnegativeeffectsforlow-wealthhouseholdsthroughafurtherdeclineinlaborincome,butbenefitshigh-wealthhouseholdsthroughhigherreturnsonsavings.

Inoursmallopeneconomymodelenergyfeaturesasbothaconsumptiongoodandafactorinputtoproduction.Allenergyusedinthedomesticeconomyhastobeimported.Householdshavenon-homotheticpreferencesoverenergyandnon-energygoodsmodelledasaStone-Gearyutilityfunction.Theyfaceidiosyncraticincomeriskthattheycanonlyimperfectlyinsureagainstduetoanoccasionallybindingborrowingconstraint.Firmsproducedomesticgoodsutilizinglaborandenergyasinputs,withlimitedsubstitutabilitybetweenthem.Whilepricesareflexibleweintroducestickywagesthroughlaborunions.WemodelmonetarypolicyasaTaylorrule,whichcanreacteithertocontemporaneousinflationmeasuresortheirforecasts.Thesemeasuresincludeheadlineinflation,definedasthechangeinaggregateprices,coreinflation,definedasthechangeindomesticgoodsprices,andenergypriceinflation.Wecontrasttheseruleswithabaselinepolicythatremainspassivebykeepingtherealrateconstant.

WecalibrateourmodeltodatafromtheEuroAreainordertoquantifytheaggregateanddistributionaleffectsofanenergypriceshock.Wetakeparticularcareinmatchingthehetero-geneityobservedinhouseholdconsumptionbaskets.InparticularweuseEurostat’s“Householdbudgetsurvey(HBS)”and“Income,wealthandconsumptionstatistics”(ICWS)tomatchanaveragehouseholdexpenditureonenergyofaround9percentandmatchthedegreeofnon-homotheticitytotargethigherenergyexpendituresofthelowestincomequintileofaround13percent.Additionally,wetargetanaverageaggregatemarginalpropensitytoconsumeofaround0.3deliveringsubstantialincomeandwealthheterogeneityinourmodel.Onthefirm

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29675

side,wecalibratethedegreeofcomplementaritybetweenfactorinputstorecentestimatesin

Bachmannetal.

(2022)andadditionallytakeintoaccountinformationbasedoninput-output

tablesindicatingthattheenergyuseinproductionisnearlydoublethatofconsumption.

Westartbyillustratingtheimportanceofnon-homotheticpreferencesandinputcomplemen-taritiesfortheaggregateandindividualconsumptionandincomeresponsetoanenergypriceshockunderourbaselinepassivepolicy.Non-homotheticityimposesaconstraintonlow-wealthhouseholds,whileelasticitiesofsubstitutioninconsumptionandproductiongoverntheabilityofhouseholdsandfirmstorespondtotheshockinrelativeprices.Weshowthatlesswealthyhouseholdssufferalargerconsumptionexpenditureshockcomparedtowealthyhouseholds,therebyfurtherraisingtheiralreadyelevatedmarginalpropensitytoconsume(MPC).Whentheelasticityofsubstitutionacrossconsumptiongoodsislarge,theenergypriceshockislesssevereforallhouseholdsastheyareabletosubstituteawayfrommoreexpensiveenergygoodstowardscheaperdomesticgoods.Similarly,ahighelasticityofsubstitutionintheproductionfunctionallowsfirmstodecreasetheirdemandforenergyandthereforemitigatesthedeclineinlabordemand,predominantlybenefitinglow-wealthhouseholds.

Turningtotheaggregateeffectsofanenergypriceshockweshowthestrongdependenceonthemonetarypolicyresponse.Wecontrastabaselineinwhichmonetarypolicykeepstherealrateconstant,i.e.isfullypassive,topolicyruleswhichreacteithertocontemporaneousorforecastmeasuresofinflation.Inouropeneconomymodel,whereallenergyisimported,anenergypriceshockisalwaysrecessionaryregardlessofthepolicyresponse,asthebenefitsfromhigherenergypricessolelyaccruetotheforeigneconomy.Incontrasttothepassivebaseline,apolicyrespondingtoeithercontemporaneousheadlineorcoreinflationraisesrealinterestrates.Higherrealratesinturninduceastrongdeclineinconsumptionandoutputthatisfourtimesbiggerthanunderthebaseline.Rulesrespondingtoeitherforecastmeasuresofheadlineorcoreinflationinsteadeffectively“l(fā)ookthrough”theinitialenergypriceincrease.Realratesriseverylittleunderthese“passive”responses,therebyalleviatingmostofthenegativeeffectsonaggregatedemand.Inturn,thedeclineinbothconsumptionandlaborincomeislesspronouncedcomparedtothebaselinerulewithotherwiseverysimilarimplications.Respondingtoenergyinflationhasremarkablydifferentimplications.Undersuchapolicy,theincreaseintherealrateisthehighestwithaninitialcompletesuppressionofenergyandthereforeheadlineinflation.However,thiscomesatthecostofastrongrecessionthatisinitiallysignificantlylargerthanunderaheadlinerule.Additionally,completelycontaininginflationintheshorttermcomes

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29676

atthecostofhigherinflationinthemedium-term,whenaspeedyrecoveryofdomesticgoodsdemandtogetherwithrisingforeigndemandultimatelyraisescoreandheadlineinflation.

Byanalyzingthedriversoftheaggregateconsumptionresponseweshowthatthenegativeeffectsofanenergypriceshockstemfromindirectnegativerealincomeeffectsbutarestronglyexacerbatedunderanactivepolicyresponsethroughdirectrealrateeffects.Wedecomposetheconsumptionresponseintoadirecteffectarisingfromchangesintherealinterestrate,anindirecteffectarisingfromchangesinlaborincomeandarelativepriceeffect.Thelattercapturesadeclineinconsumptionarisingfromtheenergypriceshock,causinghigherexpendituresonsubsistenceconsumptiontherebyleavingasmallershareofincomeforconsumptionbeyondthesubsistencelevel.Underafixedrealrate,four-fifthsandthereforethemajorityoftheconsumptiondeclineisduetoindirectincomeeffectswhereasonefourthisdrivenbytherelativepriceeffect.Sincemonetarypolicyispassive,therearenodirectrealrateeffects.Thisimpliesthattheadverseeffectsofanenergypriceshockworkpredominantlythroughareductioninrealincomewithanadditionalmarginforrisingcostsoftheconsumptionbasket.Instarkcontrast,underanactivepolicyresponse,three-fourthsofthedeclineinconsumptionisaccountedforbythedirecteffectandthereforedirectlyrelatedtotheriseintherealrate.Forecastrulesthataresufficientlypassivetriggeronlyasmallincreaseinrealrateswhichpositivelycontributestoaggregateconsumptionbyprovidinghigherreturnsonsavingswithoutadverseeffectsonaggregatedemandandthereforelaborincome.

Finally,weshowthatlow-wealthhouseholdsaregenerallyaffectedthemostbyanenergypriceshock.Absentanypolicyresponsethedeclineintheirconsumptionisthreetimeslargerrelativetohigh-wealthhouseholds.Anactivepolicyresponseamplifiestheconsumptionde-clineforallhouseholds.Althoughthisdeclineislargerforwealthierhouseholds,thedriveroftheunderlyingconsumptionstarklydifferbetweenlow-andhigh-wealthhouseholds.Low-wealthhouseholdshavetoreduceconsumptionbecauseofthestrongdeclineinlaborincome.Incontrast,wealthyhouseholdsoptimallychoosetoreducetheirconsumptionbecausehigherrealratesincentivizethemtosavemore.Forthesehouseholdspriceeffectsareimmaterialandlaborincomeeffectsarealotsmallerthanforlow-wealthhouseholds.Apassivepolicyresponseinsteaddoesnotinducea(strong)responseofrealratesandtherebydoesnotcauseastrongconsumptiondeclineforwealthyhouseholdsastheenergyshockitselfdoesnotsubstantiallyaf-fectthem.However,low-wealthhouseholdssubstantiallybenefitfromapassivepolicyresponsebecauseofthestronglymitigatedadverseeffectsonlaborincomeassociatedwithsuchapolicy.

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29677

RelatedliteratureWerelatetothreemainstrandsoftheliteratureinvestigatingtheaggre-gateanddistributionaleffectsofenergyshocksinopeneconomymodels,includingtheimplica-tionsandpropagationmechanismsunderdifferentmonetarypolicyconducts.Thecoreanalysisbuildsonanestablishedbodyofliteraturewhichfocusesonthetransmissionofoilpriceshocks

inopen-economyrepresentative-agentmodels(Mendoza,

1995;

Kose,

2002

andmorerecently

BaqaeeandFarhi,

2019)includingtheappropriatemonetarypolicyresponse(Bodensteinetal.,

2011;

Natal,

2012)

.

BlanchardandGali

(2007)studythepropagationofoilpricesinanopen

economyrepresentativeagentmodel,byincludingoilintheproductionfunctioninordertoaccountfortheroleofintermediateproductionfactors.

Bernankeetal.

(1997)conductcounter

-factualmonetarypolicysimulationsandconcludethatmonetarypolicysignificantlyinfluencesthetransmissionofoilpriceshocksintheeconomy.

Bodensteinetal.

(2011)useaNewKeyne

-sianmodelwithoilinconsumptionandproductiontoexaminetheeffectsofdifferentmonetarypoliciesinresponsetoenergyshocks,bydistinguishingbetweencoreandheadlineinflation.Theauthorsfindanoptimalresponsetoanadverseenergysupplyshockinvolvesapersistentriseincoreandheadlineinflation.

Bodensteinetal.

(2013)usingthesamemodelfindthattheeffects

ofoilshocksonaggregatedemandarerathercushionedwhenmonetarypolicyisconstrainedbythezerolowerboundcomparedtonormaltimeswhenmonetarypolicyisunconstrained.

Natal

(2012)inanoptimalpolicydesignarguesthatpolicieswhichperfectlystabilizeprices

entailsignificantwelfarecosts.Weaddtothisliteraturebystudyingenergypriceshocksinasimilaropeneconomysettingbutwithafocusonhouseholdheterogeneitywhichallowsustoalsostudydistributionaleffectsofenergypriceshocksandhowtheyrelatetodifferentmonetarypolicyresponses.Morerecently,

GagliardoneandGertler

(2023)haveestimatedaNewKeyne

-sianmodelincorporatingoilandshowingthatstudyingoilpriceshocksandmonetarypolicycombinedprovidesagooddescriptionoftherecentaggregatedata.Whileallthesepapersfocusonaggregateoutcomes,

DelCantoetal.

(2023)notablydevelopanempiricalframeworktoan

-alyzetheimpactofinflationaryshocksthroughoutthedistribution,separatelystudyingenergyandmonetarypolicyshocks.Ourpapercanbeunderstoodasastructuralcounterparttotheirempiricalapproach,withafocusonhowtheeffectsofenergyshocksareshapedbymonetarypolicy.Despitethedifferencesinapproaches,wesimilarlyconcludethatenergypriceshocksaregenerallyregressiveandthatthemonetarypolicyresponsecanhaveasubstantialimpactinshapingtheseeffects.

Wealsorelatetoagrowingliteratureanalyzingthedomesticeffectsofshocksemergingin

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29678

foreigneconomiesinthecontextofopen-economyheterogeneousagent(HA)models.

deFerra

etal.

(2020)quantifytheaggregateanddistributionaleffectsofcapitalflowreversalsinHungary,

whereagentsholddifferentamountsofforeigncurrencydebt.

Guoetal.

(2020)studythe

distributionaleffectsofinternationalshockswhenagentsdifferbytheirsectorofworkandtheirfinancialintegration,findingthatthesesourcesofheterogeneitycanplayamajorroleandcreatetrade-offsintheconductofmonetarypolicy.Otherrecentpapersstudyingtheredistributiveeffectsofexternalshocksinclude

Zhou

(2020),

Oskolkov

(2022)and

Otten

(2021)

.

Cugat

(2019)

introduceshouseholdheterogeneityinanopen-economyNewKeynesianmodelandstudyitsroleinthetransmissionofforeignshocks.

Auclertetal.

(2019)studymonetarytransmissionin

anopen-economyHANK,providinggeneralconditionsunderwhichhouseholds’heterogeneitymattersemphasizingthepresenceofastrongreal-incomechannelthatcanleadtocontractionarydevaluations.

Guntinetal.

(2020)showhowintroducinghouseholdheterogeneitycaninform

macroeconomictheoriesofaggregateconsumptionadjustmenttosuddenstops.Wecontributetothisliteraturebyexplicitlystudyingenergypriceshocksandtheiraggregateanddistributionalconsequencesaddingmonetarypolicyasasourceimpactingforeignshocks.

Third,wecontributetoanemergingliteraturestudyingenergyshocksinmacroeconomicmodelswithatleastsomedegreeofhouseholdheterogeneity.

Chanetal.

(2022)focusonthe

productionsidehighlightingthedemandspilloversarisingfrominputcomplementarityinatwo-agentNewKeynesianmodel.Theyshowthatahighercomplementarityleadstoastrongerdeclineinlabordemandhurtingconstrainedhouseholdsmoreandadditionallystudyoptimalpolicyinthissettingwithlimitedheterogeneity.Whilealsomodellinginputcomplementary,weinsteademphasizethedemandsideheterogeneityinbothconsumptionandincomeinafully-fledgedHANKmodelandcomparehowdifferentmonetarypolicyrulesbenefitorhurtdifferenthouseholdsalongtheincomedistribution.

Gornemannetal.

(2023)usingasimilar

twoagentmodelstudyhowsupplyshortagescanleadtoself-fulfillingfluctuationsandanalyzehowmonetarypolicycanremovedeterminacyrisks.Inarecentpaper,

Olivietal.

(2023)study

howmonetarypolicyshouldreacttoaggregateandsectoraldisruptionsinamulti-sectorNewKeynesianmodel.Theyfocusonananalyticalderivationoftwowedgesrelatedtoheteroge-neousconsumptionexpenditureswhenhouseholdshavenon-homotheticpreferencesandshowthatappliedtoUKdatathesewedgesarequantitativelyimportant.Wedifferfromtheirpa-perbyexplicitlymodellingenergyandconsideringshockstoenergypricesinsteadofaggregateproductivity.Asweshow,energypriceshockshaveconsiderablydifferentaggregateanddistri-

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo29679

butionalimplicationscomparedtoothersupplyshocks.Additionally,theirfocusontractableheterogeneityprecludesthemtofullystudydistributionaleffectsaswedoinourmodel.

Au-

dzeiandSut′oris

(2023)similarlyuseatractableheterogeneousagentmodel,albeitstudyingthe

incentivestoinvestinenergyabatementcapitalinresponsetoanenergypriceshock.Perhapstheclosestpaperstooursare

Auclertetal.

(2023)and

Pieroni

(2023)

.

Pieroni

(2023)builds

aclosedeconomyHANKmodeltostudyhowashocktoenergysupplyaffectsmacroeconomicoutcomes.Weinsteademployanopeneconomymodelandinnovatebyexplicitlystudyingdif-ferentmonetarypolicyrulesandhowtheyaffectbothaggregateanddistributionaloutcomes,alsostudyingthedriversofindividualconsumptionresponsesandhowtheydifferacrossthewealthdistribution.

Auclertetal.

(2023)similarlybuildanopeneconomyHANKmodelwith

differencesinthemodelsetup,e.g.abstractingfrominputcomplementaritiesinproduction.Theystudyhowtheinteractionoffiscalpolicyandmonetarypolicyspecifiedasanexogenousratepathcanmitigateenergypriceshocksalbeitsolelyfocusingonaggregateeffects.WeinsteadexplicitlystudydistributionaloutcomesandspecifymonetarypolicythroughamorecommonlyusedTaylorrulethatendogenouslyreactstoeithercontemporaneousorforecastmeasuresofinflation.

Theremainderofthepaperisorganisedasfollows.InSection

2

wepresentourtheoreticalmodelandinSection

3

wedescribethecalibrationandsteadystateofthemodel.Section

4

focusesontheimplicationsofanenergypriceshockinthecontextofdifferentmonetarypolicyframeworks,highlightingtheroleoftheelasticitiesofsubstitutioninconsumptionandproduction.Thesectionalsoexaminestheaggregateanddistributionaleffectsunderbothabaselinekeepingtherealratefixedandvariousactivepolicyrules.Finally,section

5

concludes.

2Model

InthissectionweintroduceasmallopeneconomyNewKeynesianmodelwithheterogeneoushouseholds.Energyfeaturesasbothaconsumptiongoodaswellasafactorinputtoproduction.Householdshavenon-homotheticpreferencesovernon-energyandenergygoodswithlesswealthyhouseholdsspendingalargershareoftheirincomeonenergy.Productionofnon-energygoodsrequireslaborandenergyasinputswhichcannotbeeasilysubstituted.Alaborunionflexiblysupplieslabortofirmschargingawageratethattheycanonlyinfrequentlychange,whereasgoodspricesareperfectlyflexible.Allenergyhastobeimportedfromabroadandwemodelan

ECBWorkingPaperSeriesNo296710

energycrisisasanexogenousshocktotheforeignpriceofenergy.

2.1Households

EnvironmentTheeconomyispopulatedbyacontinuumofhouseholdsofmeasureone.Householdsareinfinitely-livedandtimeisdiscrete.Thedomesticeconomyispartofacontin-uumofforeigncountriesdistributedovertheunitinterval,eachpopulatedbyarepresentativeforeignagen

溫馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
  • 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
  • 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
  • 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
  • 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。

評(píng)論

0/150

提交評(píng)論