版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
1、外商直接投資能否帶來溢出效應(yīng)?外文翻譯 外文翻譯原文are there positive spillovers from direct foreign investment?material source:journal of development economics 421993 51-74author: mona haddad , ann harrison many developing countries now actively solicit foreign investment, offering income tax holidays,import duty exemption
2、s?and subsidies to foreign firms. one reason for subsidizing these firms is the positive spillover from transferring technology to domestic firms. this paper employs a unique firm-level dataset to test for such spillovers in the moroccan manufacturing sector. we find evidence that the dispersion of
3、productivity is smaller in sectors with more foreign firms. however, we reject the hypothesis that foreign presence accelerated productivity growth in domestic firms during the second half of the 1980s. using detailed information on quotas and tariffs, we also reject the possibility of a downward bi
4、as in estimating technology spillovers because foreign investors may be attracted to protected domestic markets 1. introductiou the disappearance of non-equity sources of foreign capital in the 1980s has created a renewed interest in direct foreign investment dfi. despite the controversies surroundi
5、ng the benefits and costs of dfi, a number of developing country governments have now changed their policies from restricting towards promoting foreign investment. some countries have actually tilted the balance towards foreign firms by offering special incentives: in mexico, the maquiladora firms p
6、ay no income taxes; in much of the caribbean, foreign firms receive income tax holidays, import duty exemptions, and subsidies for infrastructure. are these subsidies justified? one benefit often cited in the literature on the gains from dfi, apart from the capital often inflows and additional emplo
7、yment, is the new technology brought in by foreign firms, it could justify some type of subsidy. this may be the rationable for goverment policies in economices as diverse as taiwan and bulgaria, which target special treatment for foreign firms in high technology sectors. technology transfer occurs
8、through many different avenues -new technology is embodied in imported inputs and capital goods, sold directly through licensing agreements, or transmitted to exporters who learn about new techniques from their foreign buyers. in other cases, learning by doing among domestic firms, combined with inv
9、estments in formal education and on-the-job training, is critical. no individual source of technology is likely to be the best; country experience suggests that the most effective diffusion of new ideas and processes probably involves a combination of all these factors. foreign investment plays an u
10、nusual role in several respects, however.first, new technology may not be commercially available and innovating firms may refuse to sell their technology via licensing agreements. mansfield and romeo 1980, for example, found that the technology transferred via multinationals was much newer than the
11、technology sold through licensing agreements. second, foreign investment may provide the competition necessary to stimulate technology diffusion, particularly if local firms are protected from import competition. third, foreign investors may provide a form of worker training which cannot be replicat
12、ed in domestic firms or purchased from abroad. the theoretical literature on foreign investment suggests that foreign investors possess some sort of intangible asset which cannot easily be sold - such as managerial skills. technology diffusion may occur through labor turnover as domestic employees m
13、ove from foreign to domestic firms existing case studies of multinational behavior do suggest that foreign investment could be an important source of spillovers. rhee and belot1990 present a number of detailed cases where foreign investors have acted as export catalysts, in some cases fueling domest
14、ic export industry where there were no domestic exports at all. mansfield and romeo, however, found that only a small share of the 15 multinationals in their survey believed that foreign investment hastened access to process technology for host country competitors. mansfield and romeo suggested that
15、 more important gains from foreign investment were likely to be through cost savings to downstream users of new products or technology transferred to upstream supplier. a number of empirical studies have attempted to directly measure the so-called spillovers from foreign investment. in an early stud
16、y, cave1974 tested for the impact of foreign presense on value-added per worker in australian domestically-owned manufacturing sectors. caves found that the diparity betweenhigher foreign and domestic value-added disappears as the foreign share of sectoral labor rises, which is consistent with posit
17、ive spillovers from foreign presence. globerman1979 replicated caves findings1974 using sector-level, cross-section data for canadian manufacturing industries in 1972. globerman, however, was able to control explicity for capital intensity in his estimation of value-added per worker. the results ind
18、icate only a weak effect-none of the proxies for foreign presence in the sector are significant at the 5 percent level. most of the empirical work on spillovers from foreign investment in developing countries has focused on mexico, which gathers manufacturing data by ownership type. blomstrom and pe
19、rsson 1983 reproduce globermans study using 1970 census data for 215 mexican manufacturing industries. controlling for capital intensity, scale effects, and worker quality, blomstrom and persson find that labor productivity is significantly higher in sectors where foreign firms employ a higher share
20、 of the labor force. blomstrom 1986 and wolff1989 find faster productivity growth and faster convergence of productivity levels in sectors which higher levels of foreign ownership. this paper, which examines the impact of foreign investment on firms in moroccos manufacturing sector from 1985 through
21、 1989, contributes to this existing literature in two respects. this is the first-sepecific attributes such as size. the panel nature of the data which combine cross-section and time series allows us to go beyond cross-section analysis comparing partial productivity measures such as labor productivi
22、ty across different firms. our results suggest that foreign firms exhibit higher levels of total factor productivity, but their rate of productivity growth is lower than that for domestic firms. at first glance, this would appear to support the catch-up hypothesis ?domestic firms, at lower initial l
23、evels of productivity, are able to increase efficiency at a faster rate. however, our tests on the presence of any spillovers from foreign presence show that although domestic firms exhibit higher levels of productivity in sectors with a larger foreign presence, they do not exhibit higer productivit
24、y growth in those sectors second, we are able to use detailed information on the level of quota and tariff protection to test whether the lack of any spilbvers stems from a tendency of foreign firms to move towards protected sectors. we do not find evidence of such positive spillovers in either the
25、protected or unprotected sectors section 2 discusses the trade and foreign investment policies in morocco before and during regulatory reform in the 1980s. section 3 examines the relative performance of domestic firms and foreign firms. section 4 measures the spillovers from foreign presence on the
26、level, growth rate, and dispersion of productivity for domestically-owned firms. this section also extends the analysis to examine whether technology spillovers are related to the degree of import protection. section 5 concludes with a discussion of the implications of these findings for policies to
27、wards multinationals 2. the regulatory framework: foreign investment and trade policy 2.1. foreign investment polocies the first major action against foreign investment in morocco took place in 1973, when the government passed the moroccanization decree, which restricted foreign ownership of cer6n i
28、ndustrial, commercial, and service activities to no more than 49 perr;nt. the main purpose of this policy was political rather than economic -to reduce the dominant role of french firmsin the moroccan economy. activities falling under the moroccanization law ilycluded textiles, clothing, footwear, l
29、eather products, travel goods, toys, fish canriing and preserving, fertilizers, edible oils, vegetable fibers, and processed fruits acd vegetables. the negative impact of this law on foreign investment is evident from the fact that even enterprises not subject to the law voluntarily handed over thei
30、r capital share to their moroccan partners a major reform uf the investment code was undertaken in 1983. it allowed full foreign ownership of moroccan companies in certain sectors especially manufacturing, eased restrictions on the repatriation of capital and divi-dends, and introduced fiscal and ot
31、her incentives for direct foreign invest-ment. the code guaranteed i foreign investment against the risks of nationalization and expropriaaion; ii unlimited transfer of dividends and profits to foreign investors; and iii the repatriation of foreign investors capital and related caoital gains. by 198
32、5, the moroccan majority-owners restrion no longer applied to any segment in the industrial sector, which meant that foreign firms could have an equity participation fo more than 49 percent. the investment code was further liberalized in 1988, administrative procedures governing the approval of dire
33、ct foreign investment were simlifide, and rules similar to those granted to nonresident foreigners were extended to nonredident moroccans.2.2. trade polocies following independence in 1956, moroccos economic development strategy was primarily based on import-substituting industrialization and agricu
34、ltural self-sufficiency in a ighly protected domestic market. for more than two deeades, trade and in ustrial policies in morocco were based on high tariffs and on quantitative restrictions in imports. furthermore, during the 1970s, the moroccan government expanded growth through high levels of pub!
35、ic spending, financed through foreign borrowing and rising receipts from phosphate exports. this culminated in a major payment crisis in 1983. as a result, the government introduced outward-oriented structural adjust-ment measures designed to eliminate the bias against export activites, liberalized
36、the import regime, and enhanced the allocative role of the financial sector. the trade reform introduced in 1983 called for the eventual elimination of the special import tariff sit, a uniform tariff levied on the c.i.f. value of imports, the lowering of the imum customs duty from 400 percent in 198
37、3 to 60 percent in 1984 and 45 percent in 1985, and a reduction in quantitative restrictions. changes in the industrial code were also undertaken to promote exports. in january 1988, the sit and the customs stamp duty were merged into what was called a fiscal levy on imports, set at 12.5 percent. co
38、ntrary to the declining imum tariff trend observed since 1983, the fiscal levy actually exceeded the sum of the two abolished taxes. this was intended to generate additionnal fiscal revenue rather than to provide prtection. 譯文外商直接投資能否帶來溢出效應(yīng)?資料來源:發(fā)展經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)雜志42(1993)51-74作者:莫納哈達(dá)德,安哈里森 許多發(fā)展中國(guó)家現(xiàn)在正積極爭(zhēng)取外國(guó)投資,提
39、供假期所得稅,進(jìn)口關(guān)稅減免,補(bǔ)貼給外國(guó)公司。其中一個(gè)原因是這些企業(yè)補(bǔ)貼,從國(guó)內(nèi)企業(yè)轉(zhuǎn)讓技術(shù),以積極的外溢。本文采用了獨(dú)特的企業(yè)級(jí)數(shù)據(jù)集,測(cè)試在摩洛哥制造業(yè)等溢出效應(yīng)。發(fā)現(xiàn)的證據(jù)表明,許多外國(guó)公司在部門的生產(chǎn)分工會(huì)更細(xì)。然后,有人產(chǎn)生了這樣的假設(shè):1980年后半期,外國(guó)公司加速了國(guó)內(nèi)企業(yè)生產(chǎn)率的增長(zhǎng)。對(duì)此,我們是反對(duì)的。利用配額和關(guān)稅上的詳細(xì)信息,我們不能低估技術(shù)溢出效應(yīng),因?yàn)橥鈬?guó)投資者可能傾向于保護(hù)國(guó)內(nèi)市場(chǎng)。 1.緒論 在上個(gè)世紀(jì)八十年代,外資來源的非股權(quán)化,重新掀起了外商直接投資的興趣。盡管對(duì)外商直接投資的效益和成本有諸多的爭(zhēng)議,但是許多發(fā)展中國(guó)家政府已經(jīng)改變限制外商投資的政策。實(shí)際上,一些
40、國(guó)家已經(jīng)傾斜于外國(guó)公司,提供他們特別的優(yōu)惠。在墨西哥邊境加工企業(yè),不用支付所得稅稅款;在大部分加勒比地區(qū),外國(guó)公司享受免繳所得稅節(jié)日,進(jìn)口關(guān)稅豁免,和基礎(chǔ)設(shè)施補(bǔ)貼。這些補(bǔ)貼是正確的嗎?外商直接投資,除了資本流入和增加就業(yè)這些好處外,常常被文獻(xiàn)引用的好處,是外國(guó)企業(yè)可以帶來先進(jìn)的新技術(shù),這可以看作是某種類型的補(bǔ)貼。這可能是政府政策的地區(qū)差異,就像臺(tái)灣和保加利亞,對(duì)外國(guó)企業(yè)的高科技領(lǐng)域的特殊待遇。 技術(shù)轉(zhuǎn)讓是通過許多不同的途徑-新的技術(shù)體現(xiàn)在進(jìn)口和資本貨物、直接賣通過技術(shù)許可,或通過從國(guó)外買家學(xué)習(xí)新的技術(shù)傳遞給出口商。在其他情況下,在國(guó)內(nèi)企業(yè)邊做邊學(xué)并結(jié)合正規(guī)教育和在職培訓(xùn),是至關(guān)重要的。個(gè)人資料來源的技術(shù)不可能是最好的, 國(guó)家經(jīng)驗(yàn)表明,
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 個(gè)人形象塑造與打扮技巧
- 青島農(nóng)業(yè)大學(xué)海都學(xué)院《材料合成化學(xué)》2023-2024學(xué)年第一學(xué)期期末試卷
- 青島農(nóng)業(yè)大學(xué)《航空材料及其應(yīng)用》2023-2024學(xué)年第一學(xué)期期末試卷
- 團(tuán)隊(duì)激勵(lì)技巧激發(fā)團(tuán)隊(duì)潛能
- 從視覺到邏輯高效的匯報(bào)制作流程分享
- 中國(guó)環(huán)境問題及其治理對(duì)策探討
- 初級(jí)丙烯顏料課程設(shè)計(jì)
- 學(xué)校課程設(shè)計(jì)指什么
- 兒童成長(zhǎng)中的社交能力培養(yǎng)
- 公司財(cái)務(wù)預(yù)算管理與編制技巧匯報(bào)教程
- 語(yǔ)文修改語(yǔ)病-三年(2022-2024)高考病句試題真題分析及 備考建議(課件)
- 中國(guó)抗癌協(xié)會(huì)胰腺癌患者科普指南2024(完整版)
- 齊魯名家談方論藥 知到智慧樹網(wǎng)課答案
- 國(guó)家開放大學(xué)電大《計(jì)算機(jī)應(yīng)用基礎(chǔ)(本)》終結(jié)性考試試題答案(格式已排好)任務(wù)一
- 最新國(guó)家電網(wǎng)公司電力安全工作規(guī)程
- (完整版)HSE管理體系及措施
- 淺談吉林省中藥材產(chǎn)業(yè)發(fā)展
- 職業(yè)生涯規(guī)劃?rùn)n案建立過程
- 圖形找規(guī)律專項(xiàng)練習(xí)60題(有答案)
- 小型步進(jìn)電機(jī)控制系統(tǒng)設(shè)計(jì)
- 普通發(fā)票銷售清單
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論